Tiebout Model: Concept, Assumptions, Equilibrium & Simple Tiebout Model

According to Tiebout, the communities have two ways to acquire more persons in their community. First, by forming a cartel and enforcing a singular tax rate among various communities. Second, is health tax competition amongst the communities to acquire the individuals to their communities. This tax competition is what Tiebout stressed in his model as an integral part of the allocation of local resources without any government provisions.

As a formal definition of local public good, it is one that, instead of benefiting the total population of consumers, it benefits only consumers in the local community. The fundamental notion here is that individuals must consume all goods- both public and private – at the same location.

Although, in many public good theories, bundling is rather implied. The Tiebout elucidated that if the public goods are local, that is, the consumption of the public goods and locational choice are bundled, then a market-type solution may exist, at least “approximately and hence no government intervention will be required.

The basic Tiebout model takes many communities offering different levels of public goods. It takes into account a unique way to come down to the optimal tax rate in a community, which is called as “voted with their feet”.

According to this, the individuals will prefer their most preferred community and reveal their demand for the public good and overcoming the greatest problem with the public goods theory, which is the difficulty of revelation of true individual preferences. The concept of foot voting can be utilised to maintain discipline in the communities.

Assumptions of Tiebout’s Model:

  1. Consumers are perfectly mobile where their preference patterns, which are set, are best satisfied.
  2. Full information knowledge of differences among revenue and expenditure patterns and how to react to these differences
  3. A huge number of communities in which the consumer-voters may choose to live
  4. All income from dividends (exogenous)
  5. There are no spillovers among communities; that is, the public services supplied exhibit no external economies or diseconomies between communities.
  6. The average cost of providing public goods as a function of population is U-shaped, i.e. there exists a cost-minimizing population size.
  7. Communities with population sizes below (above) the cost-minimizing size seek to expand (contract).

An allocation in the Tiebout model includes two standards- a consumption bundle for each consumer and a production plan for each firm. The case of a city that is too big and tries to get rid of residents is more complicated to imagine.

Nevertheless, economic forces are at work to push people out of it by making their cost of living go up. Every resident who moves to the suburbs to find better schools, more parks, and so forth is reacting, in part, against the pattern the city has to offer. The case of the community, which is at the optimum size and tries to remain so, is not hard to visualize.

Again, proper zoning laws, implicit agreements among realtors, and the like are sufficient to keep the population stable, for the community is small and easy to manage compared with the city.

Tiebout asserted that under these assumptions, efficient provision of public goods would be obtained. That is, communities would be of the optimal (cost-minimizing) size, and citizen voters would live in communities where the public good-tax bundles were optimal for them.

According to Musgrave and Samuelson, the expenditures are made by the central government. Services such as police, education, fire protection, etc., are mainly provided by the local governments. Hence, it is important to look into the activities of the local government. The expenditures made by the local government are generally more than that of the central government towards such activities.

The elements affecting the choice of a municipality by a person relies on the availability of schools and recreational activities such as golf course, parks, police protection, roads, parking facilities, etc., which will all enter into the decision-making process. Some non-economic variables will also be considered, but we are deliberately not putting much stress on such factors.

Equilibrium of Tiebout’s Model

The basic framework of the model is based on the general equilibrium model framework. So, according to the Tiebout model, there is an allocation plan and a production plan, respectively, for the consumer and firm.

Along with it, a public good bundle for the regional government and one region for each consumer. A Tiebout equilibrium is composed of an allocation, a price for each commodity, and a tax system for each region such that the following conditions are fulfilled:

  1. Consumers select their consumption bundles optimally.
  2. Consumers select their regions of residence/consumption optimally (no household wishes to move, treating as given public good levels and taxes across regions)
  3. Firms maximize profits
  4. Markets clear
  5. Each regional government balances its budget.
  6. Each regional government’s public goods and tax plan maximizes its objective

The question about the efficiency of the Tiebout model is still debated. The new efficiency margins that emerge in Tiebout models (relative to standard Arrow-Debreu type models of private good economies) are:

  1. whether the number of regions/communities is correct
  2. whether the allocation of individuals among communities is correct
  3. whether the level of provision of public goods within each community is correct

The general message from most of the Tiebout literature is that efficiency is not likely to be obtained in Tiebout equilibrium except under very restrictive assumptions. Some of the characteristics of the models that are critical to equilibrium properties consist of:

  1. the objectives of local governments
  2. the tax instruments assumed to be feasible
  3. the pattern of factor ownership
  4. the nature of local government competition

Simple Tiebout Model

An economy is composed of identical individuals, each of whom is endowed with a unit of labour that is inelastically supplied independent of residence. Labour is used to produce output, good Y. A unit of Y can be transformed into one unit of private good x or one unit of (pure) public good g. The assumptions about the Y technology are:

f(0) = 0, f’ > 0, f” < 0

Preference for each public good g and private good x for each individual i is given by u(g, xi)

If there are N people in the community, then the total the resource is

Nxi + g = f(N)

If the resources are equally divided amongst all the people in the community, the allocation is given by

xi + 𝑔/𝑁 = 𝑓(𝑁)/𝑁

Now, consider the optimal community size question. There is a tradeoff involved in increasing N in this model. The per-capita quantity of the productive good Y is decreasing in N, while the per-capita resource cost of providing a unit of the non-congestible local public good is also decreasing in N.

Pareto efficient allocation is given by the following optimization:

The planner problem is given by the following optimization,

Max u(g, xi)

s.t. Nxi + g = f(N)

First-order conditions,

Ux – λN = 0

Ug – λ = 0

λ [f’(N) xi ] = 0

Then, the first two equation implies

𝑁(𝑈𝑔/𝑈𝑥) = 1 : Samuelson Condition

From the third equation,

F’(N) = xi : Individual added until marginal product equal their allocation

Thus combining the resource constraint and the three conditions gives the following result,

g = f(N) – Nf’(N)

If workers or consumers are rewarded the marginal product of labour, then at the optimal population, the return to fixed factors (for example, land) precisely cover-ups the cost of the local public good.

Two related points need to be mentioned to show the allocative results of this model:

  1. changes in the costs of one of the public services will cause changes in the quantity produced
  2. the costs of moving from community to community should be recognized.

Both points can be illustrated in one example. Suppose lifeguards all over the country organize and accomplish upgrading their wages. Total taxes in communities with beaches will go up.

Now, residents who are mostly indifferent to beaches will be forced to make a decision. Is the saving of this added tax worth the cost of moving to a community with little or no beach?

Obviously, this decision depends on many factors, among which the availability of and proximity to a suitable substitute community is important. If enough people leave communities with beaches and move to communities without beaches, the total amount of lifeguard services used will fall.

These models, then, unlike their private-market counterparts, have mobility as a cost of registering demand. The higher this cost, ceteris paribus, the less optimal the allocation of resources.

Read More in: Theory of Public Finance

  1. Public Finance: Meaning, Nature & Scope
  2. Role of Government in Economy
  3. Role of Government in Mixed Economy: Public & Private Sector
  4. Role of Government under Cooperation and Competition
  5. Role of Government in Economic Development and Planning
  6. Concept of Public Goods, Private Goods, and Merit Goods
  7. Concept of Market Failure and Functions of Government
  8. Market Failure and Functions of Government: Decreasing Costs
  9. Market Failure and Functions of Government: Externalities
  10. Market Failure and Functions of Government: Public Goods
  11. Future Market: Meaning, Role & Uncertainty
  12. Concept of Information Asymmetry
  13. Theory of Second Best: Concept & Explanation
  14. Problem of Allocation of Resources: Public & Private Mechanisms
  15. Preferences: Meaning, Types & Problems of Preference Revelation
  16. Preference Aggregation & Its Mechanism
  17. Voting Systems, Direct Democracy, Representative Democracy, Leviathan Hypothesis & Arrow’s Impossibility Theorem
  18. Economic Theory of Democracy: Concept & Explanation
  19. Politico Eco Bureaucracy: Concept & Explanation
  20. Rent-Seeking and Directly Unproductive Profit-Seeking Activities
  21. Rationale for Public Goods: Concept & Explanation
  22. Benefit Theory or Voluntary Exchange Theory
  23. Lindahl Model: Concept, Equilibrium & Limitations
  24. Bowen Model: Concept, Advantages & Limitations
  25. Samuelson’s Model of Public Expenditure
  26. Musgrave’s Model of Public Expenditures
  27. Demand Revealing Schemes for Public Goods
  28. Vickery-Clarke-Groves Mechanism
  29. Groves-Ledyard Mechanism
  30. Tiebout Model: Concept, Assumptions Equilibrium & Simple Tiebout Model
  31. Theory of Club Goods
  32. Keynesian Principles of Stabilization Policy
  33. Difference Between Keynesian Economic Thought and Others
  34. Role of Expectations and Uncertainty in Formulating Stabilization Policy
  35. Intertemporal Markets Efficiency & Failure
  36. Liquidity Preference Theory
  37. Diamond-Dybvig Banking Model
  38. Preference Shocks, Adverse Selection & Central Bank
  39. Equilibrium Deposit Contract
  40. Social Goods and Its Effect on Stabilization Policy
  41. Effect of Infrastructural Facilities on Stabilization Policy
  42. Effect of Distributional Inequality on Stabilization Policy
  43. Effect of Regional Imbalances on Stabilization Policy
  44. Wagner’s Law of Increasing State Activities: Explanation, Graph & Criticism
  45. Peacock-Wiseman Hypothesis: Explanation, Graph & Criticism
  46. Public Expenditure: Concept, Objectives, & Public vs Private Expenditure
  47. Pure Theory of Public Expenditure
  48. Structure & Growth of Public Expenditure in India
  49. Trends, Lessons & Priorities in Public Expenditure in India
  50. Social Cost-Benefit Analysis: Project Evaluation, Estimation of Costs & Discount Rate
  51. Performance Based Budgeting and Zero Based Budgeting
  52. Theories of Tax Incidence: Concentration Theory, Diffusion Theory & Modern Theory
  53. Tax System and Its Principles
  54. Equity Principle and Efficiency Principle of Taxation: Meaning, Explanation & Examples
  55. Ability to Pay and Benefits Received Principle of Taxation
  56. Theory of Optimal Taxation: Excess Burden & Distortions of Taxation
  57. Deadweight Loss of Taxation: Causes, Measurement & Example
  58. Concept of Equity & Efficiency in Economics
  59. Trade-Off Between Equity and Efficiency: Meaning & Example
  60. Theory of Measurement of Dead Weight Loss
  61. Double Taxation: Meaning, Desirability, Forms & Solution
  62. Solution to Problem of Double Taxation: Intra-Country & International
  63. Double Taxation Avoidance Agreement (DTAA) and Indian Policy
  64. Classical View on Public Debt
  65. Compensatory Aspect of Public Debt Policy
  66. Public Debt or Borrowings: Concept, Need, Sources & Types
  67. Concept of Public Debt or Public Borrowings
  68. Need for Public Debt or Public Borrowing
  69. Sources of Public Debt
  70. Classification of Public Debt
  71. Burden of Public Debt: Meaning, Types & Explanation
  72. Debt Through Created Money or Deficit Financing
  73. Public Debt (Public Borrowings) and Inflation (Price Level)
  74. Crowding Out of Private Investment and Activity
  75. Principle of Public Debt Management and Debt Repayment

Share Your Thoughts