Problem of Choice & Production Possibility Curve
The basic economic problem is that human wants are unlimited while the wherewithal, means, or resources for fulfilling those wants are limited. Thus every society must face three problems: What to Produce, How and For Whom, which are known as the problems of Allocation, Choice of Techniques and Distribution. It is this choice problem that Lionel Robbins emphasized in his definition.
Economics studies this choice problem. One of the ways in which it does so is through the Production Possibility Curve or Frontier.
Production Possibility Curve (PPC)
This is a geometrical or graphical way of depicting this choice problem. It depicts the production possibilities or “menu”, as Paul Samuelson had put it.
Let us say that a society or economy, using all its resources fully, has the option of producing any combination out of a maximum of, say, cereals (represented by the symbol X), and a maximum of automobiles (Y).
Let us represent cereals (X) on the horizontal axis and automobiles (Y) on the vertical. Each point on the X-Y plane would then represent a numerical combination of cereals and automobiles.
Let us have a table of alternative combinations of the maximum number of laptops (Y) that can be produced along with a certain amount of cereals(represented by X) or vice versa. That is, we have a table of alternative combinations of maximum Y’s going with different X’s (or combinations of maximum X’s going with different Y’s). Each such combination can be represented as a point on the X-Y plane. Let us join them.
What we get is to get the Production Possibility Curve (PPC), also called Production Possibility Frontier.
Each point on the PPC (such as A, B, C)represents a maximum of X (at a certain Y) or a maximum of Y (at a certain X). All points below and including the PPC represents combinations of X and Y that are Attainable by the society concerned, but only points on the PPC represent points of maximum X (given the Y’s) or maximum Y (given the X’s). Points below the PPC (including the two axes and so, the origin) represent what the society concerned can produce but without using its (scarce) resources fully.
Point A (on the vertical axis and topmost left on the PPC) shows the maximum number of laptops that the country in question can produce if it produces no cereal at all!
Point B (South-East of A. lower down rightwards on the PPC) shows that the country can produce. That is, there is a trade-off or choice between the production of the two commodities.
Point C (South-East of B, further rightwards down on the PPC) shows a further trade-off. If less laptop are produced, the country’s resources can produce more cereals. This would be better from the point of view of food consumption, but computer use would suffer. What should the policy-makers choose?
Point D (South-East of C) shows a further trade-off.
Point E (further South-East and the extreme right point on the PPC, on the abscissa, with zero ordinate) shows the maximum amount of cereals the country can produce if it decides to produce no laptops at all. Will that be the appropriate policy?
The PPC thus depicts an entire array of possible choices or trade-offs for the economy.
Now, when we opt for one choice, we give up another. We forego an opportunity. The cost of opting for one choice is thus the opportunity of opting for the other. In Economics, this is given the name of Opportunity Cost.
If the country moves down from point A to B, the number of laptops it does NOT produce is the Opportunity Cost of the number of kgs of cereals that it does produce. Again if the country moves from B to C, the further number of laptops that it does not produce is the Opportunity Cost of the additional number of kgs of cereals that it does produce.
The slope or gradient of the PPC reflects the Opportunity Cost.
Usually, the PPC is bowed outwards or concave. If the slopes of points A, B, and C, D are measured by tangents drawn to the PPC at those points, the tangents will be seen to get steeper and steeper.
This happens because when the country moves from A to B, from the maximum number of laptops and no cereals to fewer laptops but some cereals at least, some of the resources (say, workers) that were being used for making laptops are moved to the production of cereals. Those computer workers who are first disposed off were probably not too efficient in the first place. So their reduction does not make too much of a dent; the slope of the PPC (as measured by the tangent at, say, B) is relatively flat.
When the country moves from B to C, let us say computer workers who are relatively more efficient than the first lot disposed of are now put to the production of cereals. Per additional units of cereal production, the reduction in laptop production is more. The slope of the PPC at C is higher than at B. The slopes get higher as we move further down the PPC, which thus has a bowed shape.
If, for some reason or the other, the economy becomes capable of producing more of X (at every given Y) or more of Y (at every given X), there is a forward shift of the PPC, reflecting Economic Growth. If the reverse happens, there is a backward shift of the PPC.
Even if the economy becomes capable of producing more of X (at any given Y other than at the corner point of maximum Y) or more of Y (at any X other than the corner point of maximum X), there occurs a forward shift of the PPC, reflecting Economic Growth. If the reverse happens, there is a backward shift of the PPC.
This is how the PPC helps the study of human choice among alternative uses of scarce resources.
Read More- Microeconomics
- Microeconomics: Definition, Meaning and Scope
- Methods of Analysis in Economics
- Problem of Choice & Production Possibility Curve
- Concept of Market & Market Mechanism in Economics
- Concept of Demand and Supply in Economics
- Concept of Equilibrium & Dis-equilibrium in Economics
- Cardinal Utility Theory: Concept, Assumptions, Equilibrium & Drawbacks
- Ordinal Utility Theory: Meaning & Assumptions
- Indifference Curve: Concept, Properties & Shapes
- Budget Line: Concept & Explanation
- Consumer Equilibrium: Ordinal Approach, Income & Price Consumption Curve
- Applications of Indifference Curve
- Measuring Effects of Income & Excise Taxes and Income & Excise Subsidies
- Normal Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
- Inferior Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
- Giffen Paradox or Giffen Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
- Concept of Elasticity: Demand & Supply
- Demand Elasticity: Price Elasticity, Income Elasticity & Cross Elasticity
- Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand
- Measuring Price Elasticity of Demand
- Price Elasticity of Supply and Its Determinants
- Revealed Preference Theory of Samuelson: Concept, Assumptions & Explanation
- Hicks’s Revision of Demand Theory
- Choice Involving Risk and Uncertainty
- Inter Temporal Choice: Budget Constraint & Consumer Preferences
- Theories in Demand Analysis
- Elementary Theory of Price Determination: Demand, Supply & Equilibrium Price
- Cobweb Model: Concept, Theorem and Lagged Adjustments in Interrelated Markets
- Production Function: Concept, Assumptions & Law of Diminishing Return
- Isoquant: Assumptions and Properties
- Isoquant Map and Economic Region of Production
- Elasticity of Technical Substitution
- Law of Returns to Scale
- Production Function and Returns to Scale
- Euler’s Theorem and Product Exhaustion Theorem
- Technical Progress (Production Function)
- Multi-Product Firm and Production Possibility Curve
- Concept of Production Function
- Cobb Douglas Production Function
- CES Production Function
- VES Production Function
- Translog Production Function
- Concepts of Costs: Private, Social, Explicit, Implicit and Opportunity
- Traditional Theory of Costs: Short Run
- Traditional Theory of Costs: Long Run
- Modern Theory Of Cost: Short-run and Long-run
- Modern Theory Of Cost: Short Run
- Modern Theory Of Cost: Long Run
- Empirical Evidences on the Shape of Cost Curves
- Derivation of Short-Run Average and Marginal Cost Curves From Total Cost Curves
- Cost Curves In The Long-Run: LRAC and LRMC
- Economies of Scope
- The Learning Curve
- Perfect Competition: Meaning and Assumptions
- Perfect Competition: Pricing and Output Decisions
- Perfect Competition: Demand Curve
- Perfect Competition Equilibrium: Short Run and Long Run
- Monopoly: Meaning, Characteristics and Equilibrium (Short-run & Long-run)
- Multi-Plant Monopoly
- Deadweight Loss in Monopoly
- Welfare Aspects of Monopoly
- Price Discrimination under Monopoly: Types, Degree and Equilibrium
- Monopolistic Competition: Concept, Characteristics and Criticism
- Excess Capacity: Concept and Explanation
- Difference Between Perfect Competition and Monopolistic Competition
- Oligopoly Market: Concept, Types and Characteristics
- Difference Between Oligopoly Market and Monopolistic Market
- Oligopoly: Collusive Models- Cartel & Price Leadership
- Oligopoly: Non-Collusive Models- Cournot, Stackelberg, Bertrand, Sweezy or Kinked Demand Curve
- Monopsony Market Structure
- Bilateral Monopoly Market Structure
- Workable Competition in Market: Meaning and Explanation
- Baumol’s Sales Revenue Maximization Model
- Williamson’s Model of Managerial Discretion
- Robin Marris Model of Managerial Enterprise
- Hall and Hitch Full Cost Pricing Theory
- Andrew’s Full Cost Pricing Theory
- Bain’s Model of Limit Pricing
- Sylos Labini’s Model of Limit Pricing
- Behavioural Theory of Cyert and March
- Game Theory: Concept, Application, and Example
- Prisoner’s Dilemma: Concept and Example