Perfect Competition: Pricing and Output Decisions

Objective of a Firm: Profit Maximization

The output determination model of a perfectly competitive firm requires a close understanding of the goals of the firm as well as the information available to it. Any business enterprise has the knowledge of its cost structure, but minimizing the cost is not the predominant objective of the firm. In economic analysis, profit maximization is usually taken to be the objective of a firm.

Profit = Revenue – Cost

Therefore, in addition to the cost structure, the firm needs to make an estimation of the revenue, which is realized by selling different quantities of the output. The quantity sold multiplied by the price charged for each unit by the firm is the revenue earned by the firm.

Revenue = Price × Quantity

Therefore, the cost and demand conditions jointly determine the profits of the firm, which, upon maximizing, gives the equilibrium output level. The question of whether firms actually seek to maximize profit has been controversial. Profit maximization as an objective of the firm is discussed in further subsections with respect to the size of the firm, control of the firm and its structure.

1. Large-sized versus Small-sized firm / Manager controlled versus Owner controlled firm

Small firms are usually owner-managed, and profit maximization appears to be a plausible objective as the profits of any firm are pocketed by the owner. However, in the case of large corporations, there is a separation of ownership and management.

When a manager has the power to take day-to-day decisions of the corporation, then profit maximization may not be the goal as these managers are salaried personnel having no direct effect of profits on their salary (except the case when salaries are in accordance with profits of the firm).

It has been suggested by William Baumol that managers of a large corporations aim at maximizing sales instead of profits. Other goals which could be pursued by the managers of a large firm could be:

  • Revenue maximization
  • Revenue growth
  • Higher payments of dividends to the shareholders
  • Maximize short-run profits at the expense of long-run profits

The above argument suggests that profit maximization is not the predominant objective of a large manager-controlled firm. But such deviation by managers from the profit-maximizing objective could not continue for long. There are several reasons why such deviation from the goal is limited:

  • The future job prospects of a manager essentially depend on how profitably the current firm is run by the manager. Therefore, they eventually resort to profit maximization as their goal.
  • If a large firm deviates from profit maximization, then eventually, its share prices will follow a downward trend. A depressed share price could lead to the replacement of the management team.
  • Usually, the salaries of managers are tied up with the profits of the firm. In such cases, the managers have a fair incentive to follow the profit maximization principle.

Thus it could be said that in any case, firms that come close to maximizing profits are likely to survive in the long run. Therefore, the working assumption of profit maximization seems quite reasonable.

2. Cooperatives

A Cooperative is an association of people or businesses owned and managed by its members for mutual benefit. For example, a food cooperative is set up to provide food to its members at the lowest possible prices. Such enterprises do not follow profit maximization as their major objective. Its purpose is to provide the best service to its members at the minimum cost.

Profit Maximization: Total Approach

Profit maximization is a common objective of firms belonging to different market forms. The goal of maximizing profits determines the equilibrium quantity supplied by the firm. Profits are defined as the difference between the revenues and costs of the firm. Suppose the firm’s output is denoted by Q, then the total revenue (TR) is defined as:

TR (Q) = P×Q

Where P is the price of the product, and Q is the number of units of output sold. Thus, TR is the product of the price of the good and the number of units sold.TR increases as the quantity sold increases.

However, the quantity is a function of price, and a downward-sloping demand curve suggests that the demand falls as the price of goods increases. Thus, the TR of a firm is a positively sloped curve, as shown in Figure 1 below.

Figure1

The total cost (TC) is also a function of output. The short-run total cost curve is shown in the figure above. A firm’s profit is the difference between revenue and cost and, therefore, is a function of output.

𝝅(Q) = TR(Q) – TC(Q)

The profit is, therefore, maximized where the difference between the total revenue and total cost is maximum.

Figure2

In figure 3 above, TR and TC curves are shown, and the corresponding profit curve is derived. From the output level 0 to Q0, the profits are negative as the total cost curve is above the total revenue curve. It implies that the revenues are not sufficient to cover the fixed and variable costs of production.

As the quantity sold increases, the total revenue increases more rapidly than the total costs, and the profits become positive. At the output level Q*, the difference between TR and TC is maximum and it is where the profits are maximized. However, if the firm sells more than Q*, the profits start to fall and eventually become negative after the output level Q1.

The bold red curve in Figure 4.3 is the profit function. It is negative at the initial output levels, then starts to increase and reaches the maximum level at Q*, after which it falls off.

Profit Maximization: Marginal Approach

The profit maximization behaviour of the firm can also be understood with the help of marginal curves. Marginal revenue (MR) is the change in revenue resulting from one unit increase in the output level sold. It is per unit change in the total revenue of the firm and is, therefore, the slope of the TR curve.

In Figure 4, the MR at point A would be the slope of the dotted line. Marginal cost (MC) is the per unit change in cost resulting from one unit increase in the output level produced. It can be read as the slope of the TC curve. In Figure 5, MC at point B is the slope of the dotted line.

Figure3

In Figure 4.3, the equilibrium has been obtained at output level Q* where the distance between TR and TC curves is maximum. At this level, the slope of the TR and the TC curves are the same (the tangents to both curves are parallel). This implies that the marginal revenue and marginal cost are the same at the equilibrium level of output.

The rule for profit maximization for any firm is MR = MC (whether the firm is competitive or not). The marginal revenue curve is derived from the demand curve; therefore, it is downward sloping whenever the demand curve is downward sloping.

However, the MC curve is U-shaped, and it has both a downward and upward curvature. Thus, equality of marginal revenue and marginal cost is not enough to maximize profits. It becomes important to check the consequence of this condition under the following two cases:

  1. Marginal cost is downward sloping.
  2. Marginal cost is upward sloping.
Figure4

In Figure 6 above, the MR curve is taken to be a straight line (the case when the price is constant for every output level). The MC curve is U-shaped and intersects the MR curve at X and Y.

According to the condition, MR = MC, both points X and Y should qualify to yield the profit-maximizing output level. However, only one of these points is profit maximizing. The firm should not stop production at Q1 as increasing the output level will add more to the revenues than to the costs, thus increasing profits.

But as the firm reaches output level Q2, it has no further incentive to increase the output. If the output increases further, the firm would add more to the cost than to the revenues, thus reducing the profit level. Hence, the profit-maximizing output level is given by point Y and not by point X.

The profit maximization condition can be summarized as follows:

Total ApproachMarginal Approach
The difference between TR and TC curves is maximumMR = MC
MC curve should be steeper than the MR curve in case the MR curve has a zero slope as under perfect competition. (or the MC curve should cut the MR curve from below).

Using calculus, the profit maximization condition can be derived as follows:

𝝅(Q) = TR(Q) – TC(Q)

d𝝅/dQ = (dTR/dQ) – (dTC/dQ) = 0

i.e. according to the first-order condition, MR = MC, and the second-order condition is

𝑑2𝑇𝑅/𝑑2𝑄 − 𝑑2𝑇𝐶/𝑑2𝑄 < 0

i.e., the slope of the MR curve < slope of the MC curve.

Thus, both conditions for profit maximization are derived algebraically.

Read More- Microeconomics

  1. Microeconomics: Definition, Meaning and Scope
  2. Methods of Analysis in Economics
  3. Problem of Choice & Production Possibility Curve
  4. Concept of Market & Market Mechanism in Economics
  5. Concept of Demand and Supply in Economics
  6. Concept of Equilibrium & Dis-equilibrium in Economics
  7. Cardinal Utility Theory: Concept, Assumptions, Equilibrium & Drawbacks
  8. Ordinal Utility Theory: Meaning & Assumptions
  9. Indifference Curve: Concept, Properties & Shapes
  10. Budget Line: Concept & Explanation
  11. Consumer Equilibrium: Ordinal Approach, Income & Price Consumption Curve
  12. Applications of Indifference Curve
  13. Measuring Effects of Income & Excise Taxes and Income & Excise Subsidies
  14. Normal Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
  15. Inferior Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
  16. Giffen Paradox or Giffen Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
  17. Concept of Elasticity: Demand & Supply
  18. Demand Elasticity: Price Elasticity, Income Elasticity & Cross Elasticity
  19. Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand
  20. Measuring Price Elasticity of Demand
  21. Price Elasticity of Supply and Its Determinants
  22. Revealed Preference Theory of Samuelson: Concept, Assumptions & Explanation
  23. Hicks’s Revision of Demand Theory
  24. Choice Involving Risk and Uncertainty
  25. Inter Temporal Choice: Budget Constraint & Consumer Preferences
  26. Theories in Demand Analysis
  27. Elementary Theory of Price Determination: Demand, Supply & Equilibrium Price
  28. Cobweb Model: Concept, Theorem and Lagged Adjustments in Interrelated Markets
  29. Production Function: Concept, Assumptions & Law of Diminishing Return
  30. Isoquant: Assumptions and Properties
  31. Isoquant Map and Economic Region of Production
  32. Elasticity of Technical Substitution
  33. Law of Returns to Scale
  34. Production Function and Returns to Scale
  35. Euler’s Theorem and Product Exhaustion Theorem
  36. Technical Progress (Production Function)
  37. Multi-Product Firm and Production Possibility Curve
  38. Concept of Production Function
  39. Cobb Douglas Production Function
  40. CES Production Function
  41. VES Production Function
  42. Translog Production Function
  43. Concepts of Costs: Private, Social, Explicit, Implicit and Opportunity
  44. Traditional Theory of Costs: Short Run
  45. Traditional Theory of Costs: Long Run
  46. Modern Theory Of Cost: Short-run and Long-run
  47. Modern Theory Of Cost: Short Run
  48. Modern Theory Of Cost: Long Run
  49. Empirical Evidences on the Shape of Cost Curves
  50. Derivation of Short-Run Average and Marginal Cost Curves From Total Cost Curves
  51. Cost Curves In The Long-Run: LRAC and LRMC
  52. Economies of Scope
  53. The Learning Curve
  54. Perfect Competition: Meaning and Assumptions
  55. Perfect Competition: Pricing and Output Decisions
  56. Perfect Competition: Demand Curve
  57. Perfect Competition Equilibrium: Short Run and Long Run
  58. Monopoly: Meaning, Characteristics and Equilibrium (Short-run & Long-run)
  59. Multi-Plant Monopoly
  60. Deadweight Loss in Monopoly
  61. Welfare Aspects of Monopoly
  62. Price Discrimination under Monopoly: Types, Degree and Equilibrium
  63. Monopolistic Competition: Concept, Characteristics and Criticism
  64. Excess Capacity: Concept and Explanation
  65. Difference Between Perfect Competition and Monopolistic Competition
  66. Oligopoly Market: Concept, Types and Characteristics
  67. Difference Between Oligopoly Market and Monopolistic Market
  68. Oligopoly: Collusive Models- Cartel & Price Leadership
  69. Oligopoly: Non-Collusive Models- Cournot, Stackelberg, Bertrand, Sweezy or Kinked Demand Curve
  70. Monopsony Market Structure
  71. Bilateral Monopoly Market Structure
  72. Workable Competition in Market: Meaning and Explanation
  73. Baumol’s Sales Revenue Maximization Model
  74. Williamson’s Model of Managerial Discretion
  75. Robin Marris Model of Managerial Enterprise
  76. Hall and Hitch Full Cost Pricing Theory
  77. Andrew’s Full Cost Pricing Theory
  78. Bain’s Model of Limit Pricing
  79. Sylos Labini’s Model of Limit Pricing
  80. Behavioural Theory of Cyert and March
  81. Game Theory: Concept, Application, and Example
  82. Prisoner’s Dilemma: Concept and Example

Share Your Thoughts