Cobb Douglas Production Function
In Economics, the Cobb-Douglas production function is widely used to represent the relationship between inputs and output in an economy. The two most important neoclassical production functions are the Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) and the Cobb Douglas.
The Cobb-Douglas production function was created by Charles Cobb (Mathematician) and Paul Douglas (Economist) in 1927. But its functional form was proposed by Knut Wicksell (Economist) in the 19th Century.
The Cobb-Douglas production function lies between linear and fixed proportion production functions with the elasticity of substitution equal to one. It is very popular among economists because of its flexibility and ease of use.
Mathematical Form:
The mathematical form of the Cobb-Douglas production function for a single output with two factors can be written as:
π = π(πΎ, πΏ, π΄) = π΄πΎπΌπΏ1βπΌ
Where,
Y: Output
K: Capital input
L: Labour input
A: Level of technology or total factor productivity (A>0)
Ξ±: Constant between 0 and 1( 0< Ξ± <1)
Constant Returns to Scale:
The return to scale is a long-run concept when all the factors of production are variable. In the long run, output can be increased by increasing all the factors of production. An increase in scale means that all factors are increased in the same proportion, and output will increase, but the increase may be at an increasing rate or at a constant rate or at a decreasing rate.
Three Situations of Return to the Scale:
(i). Increasing Returns to Scale:
Increasing return to scale occurs when output increases in a greater proportion than the increase in inputs. If all factors are increased by 20%, then output increases by, say, 30%. So by doubling the factors, output increases by more than double.
(ii). Constant Returns to Scale:
Constant Return to Scale occurs when output increases in the same proportion as the increase in input. If all factors are increased by 20%, then output also increases by 20%. So doubling of all factors causes a doubling of output, then returns to scale are constant. The constant return to scale is also called a linearly homogenous production function.
(iii). Decreasing Returns to Scale:
Decreasing return to scale occurs when output increases in a lesser proportion than the increase in inputs. If all the factors are increased by 20%, then output increases by less than 20%.
The Cobb-Douglas production function exhibits constant returns to scale. Constant returns to scale occur when output increases in the same proportion as the increase in input. Under constant returns to scale, the sum of two exponents for capital and labour is one, i.e. Ξ± + (1-Ξ±) =1.
The Constant Return to Scale occurs when output increases in the same proportion as the increase in input.
It is shown in Fig 15.1. The labour and capital are shown on X-axis and Y-axis. Y1, Y2 and Y3 are the isoquant curves showing different levels of output. Under constant return to scale, the distance between successive isoquants remains the same as we expand output from 100 to 200 to 300 units. On a straight line OR starting from the origin, the distance OA, AB and BC are all equal.
If the sum of the two exponents for capital and labour is greater than one, then the function exhibits increasing returns to scale. And if the sum of the two exponents for capital and labour is less than one, then the function exhibits decreasing returns to scale.
Isoquant is Convex to the Origin:
Under the Cobb-Douglas production function, isoquants are convex to the origin. Fig 15.2 represents an isoquant map. An isoquant map refers to the family of isoquant curves where the higher the isoquant, the higher the level of production.
In the figure, labour is measured on X-axis and capital on Y-axis. Y1, Y2 and Y3 are the isoquant curves showing various possible combinations of inputs physically capable of producing a given level of output. If you can operate production activities independently, then weighted averages of production plans will also be feasible. Hence the isoquants will have a convex shape.
The isoquant Y1 represents 100 units of output, whereas isoquant Y2 represents 200 units of output, and the level of output is higher on isoquant Y2 than Y1. Isoquant Y3 shows 300 units of output which is higher than the level of output as shown by isoquant Y1 and Y2, and so on. So, the higher the isoquant, the higher the level of output.
The isoquants under Cobb Douglas production function are convex to the origin. This occurs because of the diminishing marginal rate of technical substitution.
Here the isoquant is:
- Downward sloping.
- Convex to the origin: Diminishing MRTS.
- Higher the isoquant, the higher the level of output.
Marginal Products and Average Products:
(i). Under Cobb Douglas production function, the average product and marginal products of factor depend upon the ratio in which the factors are combined to produce output.
πππΎ = βY/βK = π΄πΌπΎπΌβ1 πΏ1βπΌ = π΄πΌ (πΎ/πΏ)πΌβ1
π΄ππΎ = Y/πΎ = π΄πΎπΌπΏ1βπΌ/πΎ = π΄ (πΎ/πΏ)1βπΌ
The average product of capital depends on the ratio of capital and labour (K/L) and does not depend upon the absolute quantities of the factors used. The same is true for labour.
(ii). The marginal product is proportional to the output per unit of its factor.
πππΎ = βY/βK = π΄πΌπΎπΌβ1 πΏ1βπΌ = π΄πΌ (πΎ/πΏ)πΌβ1 = πΌ (Y/πΎ)
ππL = βY/βL = π΄ (1-πΌ) πΎπΌ πΏβπΌ = π΄ (1-πΌ) (πΎ/πΏ)πΌ = (1-πΌ) (Y/L)
Linear in Logarithm:
The Cobb-Douglas production function is linear in logarithm.
π = π(πΎ, πΏ, π΄) = π΄πΎπΌπΏ1βπΌ
Now applying log on both sides, we get
ln π = ln π΄ + πΌ ln πΎ + (1βπΌ) ππ πΏ
Where,
- Ξ± is the partial elasticity of output w.r.t capital. It measures the percentage change in output for, say, one percentage change in the capital input holding the labour input constant.
- (1-Ξ±) is the partial elasticity of output w.r.t labour. It measures the percentage change in output for, say, one percentage change in the labour input holding the capital input constant.
The Cobb-Douglas production function is linear in parameter. It can be estimated using the least squares method.
Properties of Cobb Douglas Production Function
(i). Constant Returns to Scale:
The Cobb-Douglas production function exhibits constant returns to scale. If the inputs capital and labour are increased by a positive constant, Ξ», then output also increases by the same proportion, i.e. π(Ξ»K, Ξ»L, A) = Ξ» f(K, L, A) for all Ξ»>0.
Y = π (K, L, A) = AKΞ± L1-Ξ±
π (Ξ»K, Ξ»L, A) = A (π(Ξ»K)Ξ± (Ξ»L)1-Ξ±
= Aλα Kα λ1-α L1-α
= Ξ»A KΞ± L1-Ξ±
= Ξ»Y
β If the function exhibits decreasing returns to scale, then π(ππΎ, ππΏ, π΄) < ππ πππ πππ¦ π > 1.
β If the function exhibits increasing returns to scale, then π(ππΎ, ππΏ, π΄) > ππ πππ πππ¦ π > 1.
(ii). Positive and Diminishing Returns to Inputs:
The Cobb Douglas production function is increasing in labour and capital, i.e. positive marginal products.
(a). βY/βK > 0 πππ βY/βL > 0
π = π(πΎ, πΏ, π΄) = π΄πΎπΌπΏ1βπΌ
πππΎ = βY/βK = π΄πΌπΎπΌβ1πΏ1βπΌ
πππΏ = βY/βL = π΄(1βπΌ)πΎπΌπΏβπΌ
Assuming A, L and K are all positive and 0 < πΌ < 1, the marginal products are positive.
(b). Diminishing Marginal Products with respect to each Input: β2Y/βK2 < 0 πππ β2Y/βL2 < 0
β2Y/βK2 = π΄πΌ (πΌβ1) πΎπΌβ2 πΏ1βπΌ < 0 if Ξ±<1
Here, any small increase in capital will lead to a decrease in the marginal product of capital. Any small increase in capital cause output to rise but at a diminishing rate. The same is true for labour.
(iii). Inada Conditions
(iv). The Cobb Douglas Production Function has Elasticity of Substitution Equal to Unity
(v). Constant Income Shares of Output:
The exponent of capital (labour), Ξ± (1- Ξ±), represents the contribution of capital (labour) to output. This is the same as the portion of output distributed to capital (labour), i.e. capital (labour) income share.
π = π(πΎ, πΏ, π΄) = π΄πΎπΌπΏ1βπΌ
The real wage of labour (w) is calculated by partially differentiating Y w.r.t. L, which is nothing but the marginal product of labour (πππΏ).
π€ = πππΏ = βY/βL = π΄ (1βπΌ) πΎπΌπΏβπΌ = π΄ (1βπΌ) (πΎ/πΏ)πΌ = (1βπΌ) (Y/πΏ)
Total Wage Bill = π€. πΏ = πππΏ. πΏ = π΄ (1βπΌ) πΎπΌπΏ1βπΌ
The labour share in real National Product is = πππ‘ππ ππππ π΅πππ/π πππ πππ‘πππππ πππππ’ππ‘
= πππ‘ππ ππππ π΅πππ/π πππ πππ‘πππππ πππππ’ππ‘ = π€πΏ/π = (π΄ (1βπΌ) πΎπΌ πΏ1βπΌ)/π΄πΎπΌπΏ1βπΌ = 1βπΌ
In the same way, the capital income share remains constant at πΌ.
Read More- Microeconomics
- Microeconomics: Definition, Meaning and Scope
- Methods of Analysis in Economics
- Problem of Choice & Production Possibility Curve
- Concept of Market & Market Mechanism in Economics
- Concept of Demand and Supply in Economics
- Concept of Equilibrium & Dis-equilibrium in Economics
- Cardinal Utility Theory: Concept, Assumptions, Equilibrium & Drawbacks
- Ordinal Utility Theory: Meaning & Assumptions
- Indifference Curve: Concept, Properties & Shapes
- Budget Line: Concept & Explanation
- Consumer Equilibrium: Ordinal Approach, Income & Price Consumption Curve
- Applications of Indifference Curve
- Measuring Effects of Income & Excise Taxes and Income & Excise Subsidies
- Normal Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
- Inferior Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
- Giffen Paradox or Giffen Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
- Concept of Elasticity: Demand & Supply
- Demand Elasticity: Price Elasticity, Income Elasticity & Cross Elasticity
- Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand
- Measuring Price Elasticity of Demand
- Price Elasticity of Supply and Its Determinants
- Revealed Preference Theory of Samuelson: Concept, Assumptions & Explanation
- Hicks’s Revision of Demand Theory
- Choice Involving Risk and Uncertainty
- Inter Temporal Choice: Budget Constraint & Consumer Preferences
- Theories in Demand Analysis
- Elementary Theory of Price Determination: Demand, Supply & Equilibrium Price
- Cobweb Model: Concept, Theorem and Lagged Adjustments in Interrelated Markets
- Production Function: Concept, Assumptions & Law of Diminishing Return
- Isoquant: Assumptions and Properties
- Isoquant Map and Economic Region of Production
- Elasticity of Technical Substitution
- Law of Returns to Scale
- Production Function and Returns to Scale
- Eulerβs Theorem and Product Exhaustion Theorem
- Technical Progress (Production Function)
- Multi-Product Firm and Production Possibility Curve
- Concept of Production Function
- Cobb Douglas Production Function
- CES Production Function
- VES Production Function
- Translog Production Function
- Concepts of Costs: Private, Social, Explicit, Implicit and Opportunity
- Traditional Theory of Costs: Short Run
- Traditional Theory of Costs: Long Run
- Modern Theory Of Cost: Short-run and Long-run
- Modern Theory Of Cost: Short Run
- Modern Theory Of Cost: Long Run
- Empirical Evidences on the Shape of Cost Curves
- Derivation of Short-Run Average and Marginal Cost Curves From Total Cost Curves
- Cost Curves In The Long-Run: LRAC and LRMC
- Economies of Scope
- The Learning Curve
- Perfect Competition: Meaning and Assumptions
- Perfect Competition: Pricing and Output Decisions
- Perfect Competition: Demand Curve
- Perfect Competition Equilibrium: Short Run and Long Run
- Monopoly: Meaning, Characteristics and Equilibrium (Short-run & Long-run)
- Multi-Plant Monopoly
- Deadweight Loss in Monopoly
- Welfare Aspects of Monopoly
- Price Discrimination under Monopoly: Types, Degree and Equilibrium
- Monopolistic Competition: Concept, Characteristics and Criticism
- Excess Capacity: Concept and Explanation
- Difference Between Perfect Competition and Monopolistic Competition
- Oligopoly Market: Concept, Types and Characteristics
- Difference Between Oligopoly Market and Monopolistic Market
- Oligopoly: Collusive Models- Cartel & Price Leadership
- Oligopoly: Non-Collusive Models- Cournot, Stackelberg, Bertrand, Sweezy or Kinked Demand Curve
- Monopsony Market Structure
- Bilateral Monopoly Market Structure
- Workable Competition in Market: Meaning and Explanation
- Baumolβs Sales Revenue Maximization Model
- Williamsonβs Model of Managerial Discretion
- Robin Marris Model of Managerial Enterprise
- Hall and Hitch Full Cost Pricing Theory
- Andrewβs Full Cost Pricing Theory
- Bainβs Model of Limit Pricing
- Sylos Labiniβs Model of Limit Pricing
- Behavioural Theory of Cyert and March
- Game Theory: Concept, Application, and Example
- Prisonerβs Dilemma: Concept and Example