Cobb Douglas Production Function

In Economics, the Cobb-Douglas production function is widely used to represent the relationship between inputs and output in an economy. The two most important neoclassical production functions are the Constant Elasticity of Substitution (CES) and the Cobb Douglas.

The Cobb-Douglas production function was created by Charles Cobb (Mathematician) and Paul Douglas (Economist) in 1927. But its functional form was proposed by Knut Wicksell (Economist) in the 19th Century.

The Cobb-Douglas production function lies between linear and fixed proportion production functions with the elasticity of substitution equal to one. It is very popular among economists because of its flexibility and ease of use.

Mathematical Form:

The mathematical form of the Cobb-Douglas production function for a single output with two factors can be written as:

π‘Œ = 𝑓(𝐾, 𝐿, 𝐴) = 𝐴𝐾𝛼𝐿1βˆ’π›Ό

Where,

Y: Output

K: Capital input

L: Labour input

A: Level of technology or total factor productivity (A>0)

Ξ±: Constant between 0 and 1( 0< Ξ± <1)

Constant Returns to Scale:

The return to scale is a long-run concept when all the factors of production are variable. In the long run, output can be increased by increasing all the factors of production. An increase in scale means that all factors are increased in the same proportion, and output will increase, but the increase may be at an increasing rate or at a constant rate or at a decreasing rate.

Three Situations of Return to the Scale:

(i). Increasing Returns to Scale:

Increasing return to scale occurs when output increases in a greater proportion than the increase in inputs. If all factors are increased by 20%, then output increases by, say, 30%. So by doubling the factors, output increases by more than double.

(ii). Constant Returns to Scale:

Constant Return to Scale occurs when output increases in the same proportion as the increase in input. If all factors are increased by 20%, then output also increases by 20%. So doubling of all factors causes a doubling of output, then returns to scale are constant. The constant return to scale is also called a linearly homogenous production function.

(iii). Decreasing Returns to Scale:

Decreasing return to scale occurs when output increases in a lesser proportion than the increase in inputs. If all the factors are increased by 20%, then output increases by less than 20%.

The Cobb-Douglas production function exhibits constant returns to scale. Constant returns to scale occur when output increases in the same proportion as the increase in input. Under constant returns to scale, the sum of two exponents for capital and labour is one, i.e. Ξ± + (1-Ξ±) =1.

Constant Returns of Scale
Constant Returns of Scale

The Constant Return to Scale occurs when output increases in the same proportion as the increase in input.

It is shown in Fig 15.1. The labour and capital are shown on X-axis and Y-axis. Y1, Y2 and Y3 are the isoquant curves showing different levels of output. Under constant return to scale, the distance between successive isoquants remains the same as we expand output from 100 to 200 to 300 units. On a straight line OR starting from the origin, the distance OA, AB and BC are all equal.

If the sum of the two exponents for capital and labour is greater than one, then the function exhibits increasing returns to scale. And if the sum of the two exponents for capital and labour is less than one, then the function exhibits decreasing returns to scale.

Isoquant is Convex to the Origin:

Under the Cobb-Douglas production function, isoquants are convex to the origin. Fig 15.2 represents an isoquant map. An isoquant map refers to the family of isoquant curves where the higher the isoquant, the higher the level of production.

In the figure, labour is measured on X-axis and capital on Y-axis. Y1, Y2 and Y3 are the isoquant curves showing various possible combinations of inputs physically capable of producing a given level of output. If you can operate production activities independently, then weighted averages of production plans will also be feasible. Hence the isoquants will have a convex shape.

The isoquant Y1 represents 100 units of output, whereas isoquant Y2 represents 200 units of output, and the level of output is higher on isoquant Y2 than Y1. Isoquant Y3 shows 300 units of output which is higher than the level of output as shown by isoquant Y1 and Y2, and so on. So, the higher the isoquant, the higher the level of output.

Isoquant are Convex to the Origin
Isoquant are Convex to the Origin

The isoquants under Cobb Douglas production function are convex to the origin. This occurs because of the diminishing marginal rate of technical substitution.

Here the isoquant is:

  • Downward sloping.
  • Convex to the origin: Diminishing MRTS.
  • Higher the isoquant, the higher the level of output.

Marginal Products and Average Products:

(i). Under Cobb Douglas production function, the average product and marginal products of factor depend upon the ratio in which the factors are combined to produce output.

𝑀𝑃𝐾 = βˆ‚Y/βˆ‚K = π΄π›ΌπΎπ›Όβˆ’1 𝐿1βˆ’π›Ό = 𝐴𝛼 (𝐾/𝐿)π›Όβˆ’1

𝐴𝑃𝐾 = Y/𝐾 = 𝐴𝐾𝛼𝐿1βˆ’π›Ό/𝐾 = 𝐴 (𝐾/𝐿)1βˆ’π›Ό

The average product of capital depends on the ratio of capital and labour (K/L) and does not depend upon the absolute quantities of the factors used. The same is true for labour.

(ii). The marginal product is proportional to the output per unit of its factor.

𝑀𝑃𝐾 = βˆ‚Y/βˆ‚K = π΄π›ΌπΎπ›Όβˆ’1 𝐿1βˆ’π›Ό = 𝐴𝛼 (𝐾/𝐿)π›Όβˆ’1 = 𝛼 (Y/𝐾)

𝑀𝑃L = βˆ‚Y/βˆ‚L = 𝐴 (1-𝛼) 𝐾𝛼 πΏβˆ’π›Ό = 𝐴 (1-𝛼) (𝐾/𝐿)𝛼 = (1-𝛼) (Y/L)

Linear in Logarithm:

The Cobb-Douglas production function is linear in logarithm.

π‘Œ = 𝑓(𝐾, 𝐿, 𝐴) = 𝐴𝐾𝛼𝐿1βˆ’π›Ό

Now applying log on both sides, we get

ln π‘Œ = ln 𝐴 + 𝛼 ln 𝐾 + (1βˆ’π›Ό) 𝑙𝑛 𝐿

Where,

  • Ξ± is the partial elasticity of output w.r.t capital. It measures the percentage change in output for, say, one percentage change in the capital input holding the labour input constant.
  • (1-Ξ±) is the partial elasticity of output w.r.t labour. It measures the percentage change in output for, say, one percentage change in the labour input holding the capital input constant.

The Cobb-Douglas production function is linear in parameter. It can be estimated using the least squares method.

Properties of Cobb Douglas Production Function

(i). Constant Returns to Scale:

The Cobb-Douglas production function exhibits constant returns to scale. If the inputs capital and labour are increased by a positive constant, Ξ», then output also increases by the same proportion, i.e. 𝑓(Ξ»K, Ξ»L, A) = Ξ» f(K, L, A) for all Ξ»>0.

Y = 𝑓 (K, L, A) = AKΞ± L1-Ξ±

𝑓 (Ξ»K, Ξ»L, A) = A (𝑓(Ξ»K)Ξ± (Ξ»L)1-Ξ±

= Aλα Kα λ1-α L1-α

= Ξ»A KΞ± L1-Ξ±

= Ξ»Y

● If the function exhibits decreasing returns to scale, then 𝑓(πœ†πΎ, πœ†πΏ, 𝐴) < πœ†π‘Œ π‘“π‘œπ‘Ÿ π‘Žπ‘›π‘¦ πœ† > 1.

● If the function exhibits increasing returns to scale, then 𝑓(πœ†πΎ, πœ†πΏ, 𝐴) > πœ†π‘Œ π‘“π‘œπ‘Ÿ π‘Žπ‘›π‘¦ πœ† > 1.

(ii). Positive and Diminishing Returns to Inputs:

The Cobb Douglas production function is increasing in labour and capital, i.e. positive marginal products.

(a). βˆ‚Y/βˆ‚K > 0 π‘Žπ‘›π‘‘ βˆ‚Y/βˆ‚L > 0

π‘Œ = 𝑓(𝐾, 𝐿, 𝐴) = 𝐴𝐾𝛼𝐿1βˆ’π›Ό

𝑀𝑃𝐾 = βˆ‚Y/βˆ‚K = π΄π›ΌπΎπ›Όβˆ’1𝐿1βˆ’π›Ό

𝑀𝑃𝐿 = βˆ‚Y/βˆ‚L = 𝐴(1βˆ’π›Ό)πΎπ›ΌπΏβˆ’π›Ό

Assuming A, L and K are all positive and 0 < 𝛼 < 1, the marginal products are positive.

(b). Diminishing Marginal Products with respect to each Input: βˆ‚2Y/βˆ‚K2 < 0 π‘Žπ‘›π‘‘ βˆ‚2Y/βˆ‚L2 < 0

βˆ‚2Y/βˆ‚K2 = 𝐴𝛼 (π›Όβˆ’1) πΎπ›Όβˆ’2 𝐿1βˆ’π›Ό < 0 if Ξ±<1

Here, any small increase in capital will lead to a decrease in the marginal product of capital. Any small increase in capital cause output to rise but at a diminishing rate. The same is true for labour.

(iii). Inada Conditions

Inada Conditions
Inada Conditions

(iv). The Cobb Douglas Production Function has Elasticity of Substitution Equal to Unity

Cobb Douglas Production Function has Elasticity of Substitution Equal to Unity
Cobb Douglas Production Function has Elasticity of Substitution Equal to Unity

(v). Constant Income Shares of Output:

The exponent of capital (labour), Ξ± (1- Ξ±), represents the contribution of capital (labour) to output. This is the same as the portion of output distributed to capital (labour), i.e. capital (labour) income share.

π‘Œ = 𝑓(𝐾, 𝐿, 𝐴) = 𝐴𝐾𝛼𝐿1βˆ’π›Ό

The real wage of labour (w) is calculated by partially differentiating Y w.r.t. L, which is nothing but the marginal product of labour (𝑀𝑃𝐿).

𝑀 = 𝑀𝑃𝐿 = βˆ‚Y/βˆ‚L = 𝐴 (1βˆ’π›Ό) πΎπ›ΌπΏβˆ’π›Ό = 𝐴 (1βˆ’π›Ό) (𝐾/𝐿)𝛼 = (1βˆ’π›Ό) (Y/𝐿)

Total Wage Bill = 𝑀. 𝐿 = 𝑀𝑃𝐿. 𝐿 = 𝐴 (1βˆ’π›Ό) 𝐾𝛼𝐿1βˆ’π›Ό

The labour share in real National Product is = π‘‡π‘œπ‘‘π‘Žπ‘™ π‘Šπ‘Žπ‘”π‘’ 𝐡𝑖𝑙𝑙/π‘…π‘’π‘Žπ‘™ π‘π‘Žπ‘‘π‘–π‘œπ‘›π‘Žπ‘™ π‘ƒπ‘Ÿπ‘œπ‘‘π‘’π‘π‘‘

= π‘‡π‘œπ‘‘π‘Žπ‘™ π‘Šπ‘Žπ‘”π‘’ 𝐡𝑖𝑙𝑙/π‘…π‘’π‘Žπ‘™ π‘π‘Žπ‘‘π‘–π‘œπ‘›π‘Žπ‘™ π‘ƒπ‘Ÿπ‘œπ‘‘π‘’π‘π‘‘ = 𝑀𝐿/π‘Œ = (𝐴 (1βˆ’π›Ό) 𝐾𝛼 𝐿1βˆ’π›Ό)/𝐴𝐾𝛼𝐿1βˆ’π›Ό = 1βˆ’π›Ό

In the same way, the capital income share remains constant at 𝛼.

Read More- Microeconomics

  1. Microeconomics: Definition, Meaning and Scope
  2. Methods of Analysis in Economics
  3. Problem of Choice & Production Possibility Curve
  4. Concept of Market & Market Mechanism in Economics
  5. Concept of Demand and Supply in Economics
  6. Concept of Equilibrium & Dis-equilibrium in Economics
  7. Cardinal Utility Theory: Concept, Assumptions, Equilibrium & Drawbacks
  8. Ordinal Utility Theory: Meaning & Assumptions
  9. Indifference Curve: Concept, Properties & Shapes
  10. Budget Line: Concept & Explanation
  11. Consumer Equilibrium: Ordinal Approach, Income & Price Consumption Curve
  12. Applications of Indifference Curve
  13. Measuring Effects of Income & Excise Taxes and Income & Excise Subsidies
  14. Normal Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
  15. Inferior Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
  16. Giffen Paradox or Giffen Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
  17. Concept of Elasticity: Demand & Supply
  18. Demand Elasticity: Price Elasticity, Income Elasticity & Cross Elasticity
  19. Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand
  20. Measuring Price Elasticity of Demand
  21. Price Elasticity of Supply and Its Determinants
  22. Revealed Preference Theory of Samuelson: Concept, Assumptions & Explanation
  23. Hicks’s Revision of Demand Theory
  24. Choice Involving Risk and Uncertainty
  25. Inter Temporal Choice: Budget Constraint & Consumer Preferences
  26. Theories in Demand Analysis
  27. Elementary Theory of Price Determination: Demand, Supply & Equilibrium Price
  28. Cobweb Model: Concept, Theorem and Lagged Adjustments in Interrelated Markets
  29. Production Function: Concept, Assumptions & Law of Diminishing Return
  30. Isoquant: Assumptions and Properties
  31. Isoquant Map and Economic Region of Production
  32. Elasticity of Technical Substitution
  33. Law of Returns to Scale
  34. Production Function and Returns to Scale
  35. Euler’s Theorem and Product Exhaustion Theorem
  36. Technical Progress (Production Function)
  37. Multi-Product Firm and Production Possibility Curve
  38. Concept of Production Function
  39. Cobb Douglas Production Function
  40. CES Production Function
  41. VES Production Function
  42. Translog Production Function
  43. Concepts of Costs: Private, Social, Explicit, Implicit and Opportunity
  44. Traditional Theory of Costs: Short Run
  45. Traditional Theory of Costs: Long Run
  46. Modern Theory Of Cost: Short-run and Long-run
  47. Modern Theory Of Cost: Short Run
  48. Modern Theory Of Cost: Long Run
  49. Empirical Evidences on the Shape of Cost Curves
  50. Derivation of Short-Run Average and Marginal Cost Curves From Total Cost Curves
  51. Cost Curves In The Long-Run: LRAC and LRMC
  52. Economies of Scope
  53. The Learning Curve
  54. Perfect Competition: Meaning and Assumptions
  55. Perfect Competition: Pricing and Output Decisions
  56. Perfect Competition: Demand Curve
  57. Perfect Competition Equilibrium: Short Run and Long Run
  58. Monopoly: Meaning, Characteristics and Equilibrium (Short-run & Long-run)
  59. Multi-Plant Monopoly
  60. Deadweight Loss in Monopoly
  61. Welfare Aspects of Monopoly
  62. Price Discrimination under Monopoly: Types, Degree and Equilibrium
  63. Monopolistic Competition: Concept, Characteristics and Criticism
  64. Excess Capacity: Concept and Explanation
  65. Difference Between Perfect Competition and Monopolistic Competition
  66. Oligopoly Market: Concept, Types and Characteristics
  67. Difference Between Oligopoly Market and Monopolistic Market
  68. Oligopoly: Collusive Models- Cartel & Price Leadership
  69. Oligopoly: Non-Collusive Models- Cournot, Stackelberg, Bertrand, Sweezy or Kinked Demand Curve
  70. Monopsony Market Structure
  71. Bilateral Monopoly Market Structure
  72. Workable Competition in Market: Meaning and Explanation
  73. Baumol’s Sales Revenue Maximization Model
  74. Williamson’s Model of Managerial Discretion
  75. Robin Marris Model of Managerial Enterprise
  76. Hall and Hitch Full Cost Pricing Theory
  77. Andrew’s Full Cost Pricing Theory
  78. Bain’s Model of Limit Pricing
  79. Sylos Labini’s Model of Limit Pricing
  80. Behavioural Theory of Cyert and March
  81. Game Theory: Concept, Application, and Example
  82. Prisoner’s Dilemma: Concept and Example

Share Your Thoughts