Williamson’s Model of Managerial Discretion

Introduction

Williamson’s Model of Managerial Discretion was developed by Oliver E. Williamson in 1964. Williamson, like other managerial theories of the firm, assumes that utility maximization is the sole objective of the managers of a joint-stock organization. It is also known as the “Managerial Discretion Theory”.

Williamson emphasizes that managers are motivated by their own self-interest, and they try to maximize their own utility function. Alike Baumol’s sales maximization model, the utility maximization objective of the managers is subject to the constraint that after-tax profits are large enough to pay dividends to the shareholders.

However, it is pointed out that utility maximization by self-interest-seeking managers is possible only in the corporate form of the business organization, as there exists a separation of ownership and control.

This is basically the principal-agent problem. It explains the relationship between the principal (owner) and the agent (who performs the owner’s work). The principal-agent shows that whenever the difference between ownership and control exists, then the self-interest of the agent makes profits lower than in a situation where principals act as their own agents.

Williamson’s Theory of Managerial Discretion

Profit works as a limit to the manager’s utility maximization as the shareholders require a minimum profit to be paid out in the form of dividends. If these minimum profits are not covered, then the job security of the managers is put in danger. But, the managers are able to hold a powerful position if:

  • (i) the firm is showing a reasonable rate of growth,
  • (ii) minimum dividends are paid to the shareholders and
  • (iii) profits at any time are at an acceptable level.

Here the manager’s decision on price and output differs from the manager’s decision on price and output of a profit maximization firm.

Assumptions of Williamson’s Model Managerial Discretion:

  • (i) Imperfect Competition
  • (ii) Separation of Ownership and management.
  • (iii) A minimum profit to be able to pay to the shareholders.

The Factors that affect the Interest of Self-seeking Managers are:

  • a. Salary and other forms of Monetary Compensation
  • b. Management Slack or Non-essential Management Perquisites
  • c. Number of Staff under the Control of a Manager
  • d. The magnitude of Discretionary Investment expenditure by the Manager.

a. Salary and other forms of Monetary Compensation:

Salary and other forms of monetary compensation are one of the most important factors in determining the utility of managers. The higher the income the managers receive, the better their standard of living and status. So, the higher the salary and other monetary compensation and perks, the higher the utility of the managers.

b. Management Slack or Non-essential Management Perquisites:

The second factor that determines the utility of the managers is the amount of management slack. The management slack consists of non-essential management perquisites such as a well-furnished office, luxurious cars, entertainment expenses etc. These perks are giving them an incentive to the managers to enhance their status and prestige in the organization, which in turn contributes to the efficiency of the firm’s operation. These non-essential perquisites are also part of the cost of production of the firm.

c. Number of Staff under the Control of a Manager:

The third factor that determines the utility of the managers is the number of staff under the control of a manager. The greater the number of staff under the control of a manager, the more powerful is the manager. More staff under the manager enhances his status and prestige. According to Williamson, there exists a positive relationship between the number of staff and the salary of the managers. In the utility maximization model of Williamson, he used a single variable for the number of staff and salary of the managers as “monetary expenditure on the staff”.

d. Magnitude of Discretionary Investment expenditure by the Manager:

The fourth important factor that determines the utility of the managers is the magnitude of discretionary investment expenditure by the manager. The discretionary investment refers to the number of resources left at a manager’s disposal to be able to spend at his own discretion. This enhances his status and prestige in the organization. Here, the discretionary investment by the managers does not include those investment expenditures that are necessary for the survival of the firm. The discretionary investment by the manager includes spending on furniture, the latest equipment, decoration material etc.

Williamson’s Utility Function

The managerial utility function includes variables such as salary, status, prestige, job security and other monetary compensation. Out of these, salary is the only quantitative variable which is measurable. On the other hand, all other variables except salary are non-quantifiable, i.e. not measurable.

In the utility maximization model of Williamson, he used a single variable for the number of staff and salary of the managers as “monetary expenditure on the staff”. The utility function of managers is a function of salary, monetary expenditure on the staff and discretionary investment.

𝑈 = 𝑓1(𝑆, 𝑀, 𝐼𝐷)

Where,

U is utility

S is monetary expenditure on the staff

M is the management slack.

𝐼𝐷 is a discretionary investment.

Here, the variables expenditure on staff salary, management slack and discretionary investment is used the unquantifiable concepts like power, status, job security, dominance etc. The variable expenditure on staff, management slack and disinvestment can be assigned some nominal values.

There exists a positive relationship between decision variables (S, M and 𝐼𝐷 ) and utility. Any increase in the decision variables increases the utility of the managers. But the firm always chooses their values subject to the constraint, S≥0 and D≥0. Williamson also assumes that the law of diminishing marginal utility applies so that when additions are made to each of the decision variables S, M and 𝐼𝐷, they yield smaller increments to the utility to the manager.

The demand curve faced by the firm is downward sloping:

Under Williamson’s model, the demand curve faced by the firm is downward sloping. The demand function can be written as:

Q = 𝑓2 (P, S, Ɛ)

P = 𝑓3 (Q, S, Ɛ)

Where,

Q is output

P is price

S is staff expenditure

Ɛ the demand-shift parameter reflects autonomous changes in demand

The demand curve is negatively sloped, implying that price and quantity have a negative relationship. i.e., 𝜕𝑃/𝜕𝑄 < 0.

When the prices increase, the quantity decreases, and when the price decreases, the quantity increases. It is also assumed that demand is positively related to staff expenditure and to the demand shift parameter ε. Thus,

𝜕𝑃/𝜕𝑆 > 0 𝑎𝑛𝑑 𝜕𝑃/𝜕Ɛ > 0

Any increase in staff spending causes an upward shift in the demand curve, allowing for a higher price to be charged. Any other change in the demand shift parameter that causes the demand curve to shift upward has the same effect. It could be an increase in income, a shift in taste in favour of a product, or something else.

Cost of Production:

The total cost of production is assumed to be an increasing function of output. This can be expressed as:

C = 𝑓4 (Q)

Where,

C is cost

Q is output

The total cost increases with the increase in the level of output, i.e. 𝜕𝐶/𝜕𝑄 > 0.

Concept of Profit in the Williamson’s Model:

The various concepts of profit used in the Williamson model need to be understood clearly before moving to the main model. Williamson has put forth four main concepts of profits. These are actual profit, discretionary profit, reported profit and minimum profit.

(i) Actual profit (π):

The actual profit is defined as the revenue from sales less the production costs and the staff expenditure.

π = R – C – S

Where,

R is revenue,

C is the cost of production and

S is the staff expenditure.

(ii) Reported Profit (πR):

This is the profit reported to the tax authorities. Reported profit (πR) is the difference between actual profits and supplementary or nonessential managerial emoluments as represented by the management slack. It is the actual profit minus the managerial emoluments (M), which are tax-deductible. So,

πR = π – M = R – C – S – M

(iii) Minimum Profit (π0):

Minimum profit (π0) is the number of profits (after tax) which is required to be paid as an acceptable dividend to the shareholders of the firm. Suppose the shareholders do not get reasonable dividends. In that case, they may sell their shares and thereby expose the firm to the risk of being taken over by others, or alternatively, they will vote for a change of top management. Both of these actions by the shareholders will reduce the job security of the top managerial team.

Hence, some minimum profits should be earned by the manager for the shareholders in the form of dividends to keep them satisfied. Through this, he can ensure his job safety. To meet this objective, the reported profits must be at least as high as the minimum profit (π0) plus the tax (T) that must be paid to the government. This is mathematically expressed as:

πR ≥ π0 + T

The tax function is of the form T = Ť + t. πR

Where,

t is the marginal tax rate or unit profit tax and

Ť is the lump-sum tax.

(iv) Discretionary profit (πD):

Discretionary profit is the amount of profit left after subtracting from the actual profit (π), the minimum profit requirement (π0) and the tax (T). It can be expressed as:

πD = π – π0 – T

(v) Discretionary Investment (ID):

Discretionary investment is the amount left from the reported profit after subtracting the minimum profit (π0) and the tax (T). It can be expressed as:

ID = πR – π0 – T

Discretionary profit is different from discretionary investment. Discretionary profits are the amount left after minimum profit (π0) and tax (T) are deducted from actual profits (πD = π – π0 – T) but discretionary investment equals the amount left from the reported profit after subtracting the minimum profit (π0) and the tax (T). Thus, we have discretionary investment

ID = πR – π0 – T

Since the difference between reported profits (πR) and actual profits (π) arises due to management slack and discretionary profits. It can be written as πD = ID + Amount of management slack. Thus, if management slack is zero, then

πR = π and πD = ID

Simplified Model of Williamson’s Managerial Discretion

Under Willaimson’s model, the objective is the maximisation of the utility function subject to the minimum profit constraint. The minimum profit should be such that it is sufficient to pay satisfactory profit to shareholders and pay for necessary investments. Here we are taking a simple case where there is no management slack, i.e. M=0.

Objective Max U = f (S, 𝐼𝐷)

Subject to π ≥ π0 + T

As there is no management slack, so the discretionary investment absorbs all the discretionary profit. Thus the managerial utility function can be written as-

U = f [S, ( π – π0 + T)]

Here, we are also assuming that there is no lump sum tax, i.e. Ť=0, so that T=t π. Thus,

U = f [S, (1 – t) π – π0 ]

Where (1-t)π – π0 is the discretionary profit πD.

Graphical Representation of the Williamson’s Model:

The graphical representation of the equilibrium of the firm requires the construction of the indifference curves map of managers and the profit curve. An indifference map is a family of indifference curves. An indifference curve is a curve which shows different combinations of two goods yielding the same level of satisfaction to the consumer.

In other words, it identifies the various combinations of goods among which the consumer is indifferent. Here, the indifference curve under the Williamson model shows the relationship between monetary expenditure on the staff and discretionary investment. These are the two variables that determine the utility function of the managers.

The indifference curve is shown in the figure where staff expenditure (S) is measured on the x-axis and discretionary profit (πD) on the y-axis. Each indifference curve shows various combinations of staff expenditure (S) and discretionary profit (πD), which give the same level of satisfaction to the managers.

Consider the Figure below:

Indifference Map
Indifference Map

It is assumed that the indifference curves of managers are of well behaved:

  • Indifference curves are downward sloping.
  • They are convex to the origin, implying a diminishing marginal rate of substitution of staff expenditure and discretionary profit.
  • Two indifference families of indifference curves can never intersect each other.
  • The higher the indifference curve higher is the level of satisfaction.
  • The indifference curves do not intersect the axes.

The indifference curves do not intersect the axes. This is a very important property and needs to be explained properly. We have seen that expenditure on staff and discretionary profit are positively related to the utility function of the managers.

Any increase in expenditure on staff or discretionary profit or in both results in an increase in the satisfaction of the managers by increasing the utility. This assumption restricts the choice of managers to positive levels of both staff expenditures and discretionary profits, implying that the firm will choose values of πD and S ‘that will yield positive utility.

It is shown in the figure below. Suppose the indifference curve does not intersect the axes. In that case, the model excludes the corner solutions, such as points A, B, C, D etc., where discretionary profit (πD) would be zero in the final equilibrium of the firm.

Indifference curves do not intersect
Indifference curves do not intersect

We have derived the indifference curve of the managers and have seen that they are well-behaved. Now let us determine the profit function and then the equilibrium analysis of the firm. The relationship between S, staff expenditure, and πD, discretionary profit, is determined by the profit function.

The profit function explains the relationship between profit and output. We have seen that output is a function of the price of the product, expenditure on staff and the demand shift parameter. Thus, the profit function is a function of the price of the product, expenditure on staff and the demand shift parameter

π = ƒ(Q) = f(P, S, Ɛ)

Where,

π is profit,

Q is output

P is price

S is expenditure on staff

Ɛ demand-shift parameter reflecting autonomous changes in demand

The profit function which explains the relationship between π0 and S is shown below in the Figure below:

Profit curve
Profit curve

We can see from the figure that the profit curve initially rises, reaches a maximum and then falls thereafter as the level of production increases. It starts increasing from point a, reaches the maximum at point b and then starts falling and becomes negative after reaching point c. So, initially, both discretionary profits and staff expenditures increase with the level of production.

This increase continues till the maximum point on the profit curve. Beyond point b, where with the increase in production profit curve starts falling, and staff expenditures continue to increase. If these expenditures continue to increase and exceed point ‘c’, then the minimum profit constraint is not satisfied. So the region before point ‘a’ and to the right of ‘c’ are not feasible solutions.

It should be clear from the above discussion that the drawn profit curve does not include the minimum profit requirement π0. Williamson’s model implies higher output, lower price and lower level of profit than the profit-maximization model.

Read More- Microeconomics

  1. Microeconomics: Definition, Meaning and Scope
  2. Methods of Analysis in Economics
  3. Problem of Choice & Production Possibility Curve
  4. Concept of Market & Market Mechanism in Economics
  5. Concept of Demand and Supply in Economics
  6. Concept of Equilibrium & Dis-equilibrium in Economics
  7. Cardinal Utility Theory: Concept, Assumptions, Equilibrium & Drawbacks
  8. Ordinal Utility Theory: Meaning & Assumptions
  9. Indifference Curve: Concept, Properties & Shapes
  10. Budget Line: Concept & Explanation
  11. Consumer Equilibrium: Ordinal Approach, Income & Price Consumption Curve
  12. Applications of Indifference Curve
  13. Measuring Effects of Income & Excise Taxes and Income & Excise Subsidies
  14. Normal Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
  15. Inferior Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
  16. Giffen Paradox or Giffen Goods: Income & Substitution Effects
  17. Concept of Elasticity: Demand & Supply
  18. Demand Elasticity: Price Elasticity, Income Elasticity & Cross Elasticity
  19. Determinants of Price Elasticity of Demand
  20. Measuring Price Elasticity of Demand
  21. Price Elasticity of Supply and Its Determinants
  22. Revealed Preference Theory of Samuelson: Concept, Assumptions & Explanation
  23. Hicks’s Revision of Demand Theory
  24. Choice Involving Risk and Uncertainty
  25. Inter Temporal Choice: Budget Constraint & Consumer Preferences
  26. Theories in Demand Analysis
  27. Elementary Theory of Price Determination: Demand, Supply & Equilibrium Price
  28. Cobweb Model: Concept, Theorem and Lagged Adjustments in Interrelated Markets
  29. Production Function: Concept, Assumptions & Law of Diminishing Return
  30. Isoquant: Assumptions and Properties
  31. Isoquant Map and Economic Region of Production
  32. Elasticity of Technical Substitution
  33. Law of Returns to Scale
  34. Production Function and Returns to Scale
  35. Euler’s Theorem and Product Exhaustion Theorem
  36. Technical Progress (Production Function)
  37. Multi-Product Firm and Production Possibility Curve
  38. Concept of Production Function
  39. Cobb Douglas Production Function
  40. CES Production Function
  41. VES Production Function
  42. Translog Production Function
  43. Concepts of Costs: Private, Social, Explicit, Implicit and Opportunity
  44. Traditional Theory of Costs: Short Run
  45. Traditional Theory of Costs: Long Run
  46. Modern Theory Of Cost: Short-run and Long-run
  47. Modern Theory Of Cost: Short Run
  48. Modern Theory Of Cost: Long Run
  49. Empirical Evidences on the Shape of Cost Curves
  50. Derivation of Short-Run Average and Marginal Cost Curves From Total Cost Curves
  51. Cost Curves In The Long-Run: LRAC and LRMC
  52. Economies of Scope
  53. The Learning Curve
  54. Perfect Competition: Meaning and Assumptions
  55. Perfect Competition: Pricing and Output Decisions
  56. Perfect Competition: Demand Curve
  57. Perfect Competition Equilibrium: Short Run and Long Run
  58. Monopoly: Meaning, Characteristics and Equilibrium (Short-run & Long-run)
  59. Multi-Plant Monopoly
  60. Deadweight Loss in Monopoly
  61. Welfare Aspects of Monopoly
  62. Price Discrimination under Monopoly: Types, Degree and Equilibrium
  63. Monopolistic Competition: Concept, Characteristics and Criticism
  64. Excess Capacity: Concept and Explanation
  65. Difference Between Perfect Competition and Monopolistic Competition
  66. Oligopoly Market: Concept, Types and Characteristics
  67. Difference Between Oligopoly Market and Monopolistic Market
  68. Oligopoly: Collusive Models- Cartel & Price Leadership
  69. Oligopoly: Non-Collusive Models- Cournot, Stackelberg, Bertrand, Sweezy or Kinked Demand Curve
  70. Monopsony Market Structure
  71. Bilateral Monopoly Market Structure
  72. Workable Competition in Market: Meaning and Explanation
  73. Baumol’s Sales Revenue Maximization Model
  74. Williamson’s Model of Managerial Discretion
  75. Robin Marris Model of Managerial Enterprise
  76. Hall and Hitch Full Cost Pricing Theory
  77. Andrew’s Full Cost Pricing Theory
  78. Bain’s Model of Limit Pricing
  79. Sylos Labini’s Model of Limit Pricing
  80. Behavioural Theory of Cyert and March
  81. Game Theory: Concept, Application, and Example
  82. Prisoner’s Dilemma: Concept and Example

Share Your Thoughts