Diamond-Dybvig Banking Model
This model was developed by Douglas Diamond and Philip Dybvig in the early 1980s. The model was published in 1983 by Douglas W. Diamond of the University of Chicago and Philip .H. Dybvig of then Yale University and now of Washington University in St. Louis.
The model primarily shows how an institution with long-maturity assets and short-maturity liabilities can be unstable. It is a simple model that captures an intertemporal aspect of consumption and investment. It further explains the bank runs and related financial crises. The model exhibits how banks’ portfolios of illiquid assets like mortgages or business loans and liquid liabilities like deposits, which can be withdrawn anytime, would lead to a situation of panic among depositors.
The model emphasizes that all business investments often require expenditure in the present in order to obtain results in future. Therefore, investors prefer loans with long maturity, implying low liquidity. The same rule is applied to individuals looking for finance housing or automobiles. While individual cavers, including both households and firms, may have sudden requirements of funds due to unforeseen and unpredictable needs, therefore they require funds which permit immediate access to deposits, implying that they would prefer short-maturity deposit accounts.
Since banks act as intermediaries between savers who prefer liquid assets and borrowers who prefer long-maturity loans, the banks, therefore, play a valuable role by channelling funds from individual deposits into loans for borrowers. Banks help depositors save money on transaction costs they will have to pay while lending to investors directly, while investors will only pay off in the future. Since banks provide valuable services to both, they can charge higher interest rates on loans than they pay on deposits and thus earn profits on margin.
As far as the Central bank is concerned, Diamond and Dybvig consider a role for central bank policy originating from the central bank’s superior ability to make payoffs to depositors contingent on realized aggregate outcome. Keeping this theoretical background in consideration, the model can now be illustrated as follows.
Let us consider the three time periods: 0, 1 and 2. There are N consumers where N is very large, and each consumer is endowed with one unit of a good in period 0, which can serve as input to production. The production technology takes one unit from period 0 and converts it into 1+r units of consumption goods in period 2. If production is interrupted, then nothing is produced in period 2.
A consumer may wish to consume early in period 1 or to consume late in period 2. However, in period 0, individual consumers do not know whether they are early or late consumers; they will get to know this in period 1. In period 0, each consumer knows that he has a probability t of being an early consumer and a probability (1-t) of being a late consumer.
Further, in period 1, t*N consumers learned that they were early consumers, and (1-t) N consumers came to know that they were late consumers. 0 < t <1, the production technology captures utility in a simple way that it reflects investing in long-maturity assets that could be sold with some loss before it mature. Such production technology takes care of the possibility that the consumer might consume early, taking into account the need for liquid assets required for unforeseen circumstances.
A consumer receives a satisfaction or utility given by U(c) where U is the Utility function and c is consumption. The Utility function is assumed to be concave, implying that the marginal utility of consumption declines as consumption increases. The Marginal Utility of consumption is given by MUc. Fig (1)
Under uncertainty, a consumer maximizes the expected utility given by
Expected Utility = tU (c1) + (1- t) U (c2) (Eq-1)
Where c1 is consumption if the consumer consumes in an early period and c2 is consumption if the consumer is a late consumer. Therefore, expected utility is a weighted average of utilities that occur over time, and weights are probabilities. The consumer’s expected utility preferences can be represented in terms of indifference curves with c1 as early consumption and c2 as late consumption, as shown in Figure (2).
These indifference curves are downward-sloping and convex. The marginal rate of substitution of early consumption for late consumption for the consumer is given by:
Where MRS c1,c2 is minus the slope of the indifference curve in Fig (2)
When c1=c2, it implies that early consumption and late consumption are equal. This further means MUc1=MUc2 because if consumption is the same, the marginal utility of consumption is also the same.
MRS c1,c2 = t/(1-t) (Eq-3)
- The consumer invests one unit of endowment in the technology in period 0.
- The consumer in period 1 interrupts the technology and is able to consume c1=1
- If the consumer is a late consumer, then technology is not interrupted, and the consumer gets c2=1+r in period 2 when the investment matures.
The above model can also be represented as follows: there is an agent who has an initial endowment of one unit in period 1 and none in subsequent periods. The agent deposits this endowment with an intermediary in period 0 in return for consumption at periods 1 and 2. The intermediary has access to two investment technologies.
The first corresponding to short-term asset yields one unit of consumption in period 1 for every unit of investment at the beginning of that period. The second corresponds to investment in the long–term asset yields R>1 unit of consumption in period 2 for every unit of investment in period 1. Individuals are also able to store consumption between period 1 and period 2. The cross-section distribution of preference shocks realized at period 1 is the same as the probability distribution of these shocks for an individual agent at period 0.
In exchange for deposits, the intermediary offers each agent a contract which allows him to withdraw either c1 units of consumption in period 1 or c2 units in period 2. In order to finance withdrawals, the intermediary liquidates L units per capita in period 1 and hence receives R(1-L) units per capita in period 2.
The intermediary chooses (c1,c2, L) to maximize the ex-ante expected utility of individual agents. Then, it solves the problem.
Max tU (c1) + (1-t) U (c2) (Eq-4)
Subject to t1 c1 = L
The following are the first-order conditions
- U’(c1*) = R U’( c2*)
- C1* = L*/t and c2 = (1 – L*) R/(1-t)
Clearly, c1*>c2* is implied by the above (1) and (2) and the condition that R>1.
A sufficient condition for c2*/ c1* to be less than R is that U’ ( c ) be decreasing in c. Thus, if U has a coefficient of relative risk aversion greater than unity, then early consumers will share higher returns on illiquid assets.
The first best allocation (c*1,c*2, L* ) is obtained by (1) and (2).
There are two Pareto-ranked Nash equilibrium, according to Diamond and Dybvig. When the agents who genuinely have a preference for early consumption choose to make an early withdrawal. While the second best Pareto-dominated equilibrium occurs when agents who actually prefer late consumption but fear withdrawal by others of the same type also choose to withdraw early. The inefficiency of these bank runs arises directly from premature and unnecessary disinvestment of higher-yielding assets.
Read More in: Theory of Public Finance
- Public Finance: Meaning, Nature & Scope
- Role of Government in Economy
- Role of Government in Mixed Economy: Public & Private Sector
- Role of Government under Cooperation and Competition
- Role of Government in Economic Development and Planning
- Concept of Public Goods, Private Goods, and Merit Goods
- Concept of Market Failure and Functions of Government
- Market Failure and Functions of Government: Decreasing Costs
- Market Failure and Functions of Government: Externalities
- Market Failure and Functions of Government: Public Goods
- Future Market: Meaning, Role & Uncertainty
- Concept of Information Asymmetry
- Theory of Second Best: Concept & Explanation
- Problem of Allocation of Resources: Public & Private Mechanisms
- Preferences: Meaning, Types & Problems of Preference Revelation
- Preference Aggregation & Its Mechanism
- Voting Systems, Direct Democracy, Representative Democracy, Leviathan Hypothesis & Arrow’s Impossibility Theorem
- Economic Theory of Democracy: Concept & Explanation
- Politico Eco Bureaucracy: Concept & Explanation
- Rent-Seeking and Directly Unproductive Profit-Seeking Activities
- Rationale for Public Goods: Concept & Explanation
- Benefit Theory or Voluntary Exchange Theory
- Lindahl Model: Concept, Equilibrium & Limitations
- Bowen Model: Concept, Advantages & Limitations
- Samuelson’s Model of Public Expenditure
- Musgrave’s Model of Public Expenditures
- Demand Revealing Schemes for Public Goods
- Vickery-Clarke-Groves Mechanism
- Groves-Ledyard Mechanism
- Tiebout Model: Concept, Assumptions Equilibrium & Simple Tiebout Model
- Theory of Club Goods
- Keynesian Principles of Stabilization Policy
- Difference Between Keynesian Economic Thought and Others
- Role of Expectations and Uncertainty in Formulating Stabilization Policy
- Intertemporal Markets Efficiency & Failure
- Liquidity Preference Theory
- Diamond-Dybvig Banking Model
- Preference Shocks, Adverse Selection & Central Bank
- Equilibrium Deposit Contract
- Social Goods and Its Effect on Stabilization Policy
- Effect of Infrastructural Facilities on Stabilization Policy
- Effect of Distributional Inequality on Stabilization Policy
- Effect of Regional Imbalances on Stabilization Policy
- Wagner’s Law of Increasing State Activities: Explanation, Graph & Criticism
- Peacock-Wiseman Hypothesis: Explanation, Graph & Criticism
- Public Expenditure: Concept, Objectives, & Public vs Private Expenditure
- Pure Theory of Public Expenditure
- Structure & Growth of Public Expenditure in India
- Trends, Lessons & Priorities in Public Expenditure in India
- Social Cost-Benefit Analysis: Project Evaluation, Estimation of Costs & Discount Rate
- Performance Based Budgeting and Zero Based Budgeting
- Theories of Tax Incidence: Concentration Theory, Diffusion Theory & Modern Theory
- Tax System and Its Principles
- Equity Principle and Efficiency Principle of Taxation: Meaning, Explanation & Examples
- Ability to Pay and Benefits Received Principle of Taxation
- Theory of Optimal Taxation: Excess Burden & Distortions of Taxation
- Deadweight Loss of Taxation: Causes, Measurement & Example
- Concept of Equity & Efficiency in Economics
- Trade-Off Between Equity and Efficiency: Meaning & Example
- Theory of Measurement of Dead Weight Loss
- Double Taxation: Meaning, Desirability, Forms & Solution
- Solution to Problem of Double Taxation: Intra-Country & International
- Double Taxation Avoidance Agreement (DTAA) and Indian Policy
- Classical View on Public Debt
- Compensatory Aspect of Public Debt Policy
- Public Debt or Borrowings: Concept, Need, Sources & Types
- Concept of Public Debt or Public Borrowings
- Need for Public Debt or Public Borrowing
- Sources of Public Debt
- Classification of Public Debt
- Burden of Public Debt: Meaning, Types & Explanation
- Debt Through Created Money or Deficit Financing
- Public Debt (Public Borrowings) and Inflation (Price Level)
- Crowding Out of Private Investment and Activity
- Principle of Public Debt Management and Debt Repayment